Do investment programs create more jobs in tight or in slack labor markets? We study this question using data from a large, long-term photovoltaic invest scheme in Germany. Comparing counties with high and low unemployment both over time and across space, we find that photovoltaic installations created at least twice as many jobs in slack than in tight labor markets. Our results suggest that the differences in job-creation are not driven by changes in the composition or prices of investment, capital-labor substitution, or regional migration. This leaves crowding-out as the most plausible mechanism.
|
Is compulsory licensing an effective antitrust remedy to increase innovation? To answer this question, we analyze the 1956 consent decree which settled an antitrust lawsuit against Bell, a vertically integrated monopolist charged with foreclosing the telecommunications equipment market. Bell was forced to license all its existing patents royalty-free, including those not related to telecommunications. We show that this led to a long-lasting increase in innovation but only in markets outside the telecommunications industry. Within telecommunications, where Bell continued to exclude competitors, we find no effect. Compulsory licensing is an effective antitrust remedy only if incumbents cannot foreclose the product markets.
|
Winner of the AEJ Best Paper Awards
Link to published version (complimentary access) Download VoxEU Link to CEPR Discussion Paper American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 12.4 (2020): 328-59. |
We provide the first measurement of knowledge spillovers from venture capitalfinanced companies onto the patenting activities of other companies. These spillovers are nine times larger than those generated by the corporate R&D of established companies. The effects are heterogenous, depending on who generates the spillover and who is the likely recipient. In general, complex product industriestend to be more conducive to spillovers than discrete product industries. Spillovers are stronger for investments in a small set of start-ups that are characterized by an inventor team with prior patenting experience and that have a patented technology before receiving their first round of investment. This points to a complementarity between the supply of venture capital on the one hand and access to experience and technology on the other hand. The methodological contribution of our paper is the development of a novel definition of the spillover pool that combines elements of the citation-based and technological proximity-based approaches. |
How important is information disclosure through patents for subsequent innovation? To answer this
question, we examine the expansion of the USPTO Patent Library system after 1975. Before the Internet, patent libraries gave inventors access to patent documents. We find that after patent library opening, local patenting increases by 17% relative to control regions. Additional analyses suggest that the disclosure of technical information is the mechanism underlying this effect: inventors start to cite more distant prior art and the effect ceases after the introduction of the Internet. Our analyses thus provide evidence that disclosure plays an important role in cumulative innovation. |
It is well documented that graduates enter different occupations
in recessions than in booms. In our article, we examine the impact of the
resulting change in the allocation of talent for long-term productivity and
output in a sector. In a setting where output can be quantitatively and
qualitatively measured, we find evidence that talent flows to stable sectors in
recessions and to cyclical sectors in booms: economists starting or graduating
from their PhD in a recession are significantly more productive in academia
over the long term than economists starting or graduating in a boom.
|
Motivated
by the differences in innovation intensity across countries, this paper
evaluates the role of contract enforcement for R&D investments. If
contracts for inputs are incomplete and contract enforcement is weak,
innovative companies can be exploited by their suppliers. This reduces the incentive
to invest in R&D. We find evidence supporting this prediction in the data:
R&D investment increases with the quality of the judicial system and this
effect is particularly strong in industries that depend more on bilateral
contracts to acquire inputs and in which vertical integration is not a
viable option.
|
This article examines the impact of a credit crunch on
market structure. We construct and simulate a dynamic model of a duopolistic
industry in which firms’ investments in capacity are constrained by the
availability of credit. In such an industry, the dynamic interaction of credit
limits and the competitive responses of firms turn out to be a powerful transmission
mechanism by which the effects of shocks persist and are amplified. We show
that a small, temporary shock to one firm’s capacity can lead to its market
exit, even if it is equally productive as the remaining incumbent.
Consequently, if a recession is accompanied by a credit crunch, its cleansing
effect might lead to monopolization of markets.
|
Our study shows a negative association between the number and success of venture capital
investments and the capital gains tax rate. This analysis uses the investment
and tax data of 32 countries from 2000 to 2012. Our results support the
theoretical predictions that higher capital gains tax rates are associated with
fewer start-ups financed and a lower probability of receiving follow-up
funding. However, if a company receives its initial funding despite a higher
tax burden, its probability of success increases. Therefore, our findings are
in line with a selection effect of taxes.
|